Shipping Climate Architecture

Shipping climate architectureArchitecture for Mitigation, Adaptation, and Technology Transformation for International Transport (0.4 Mb).
The architecture covers emissions from international maritime transport and potentially from aviation in the post-2012 climate agreement.
The potentially breakthrough GbD approach is introduced in section 4.1.5 Improving the Differentiation Further.
This was our approach tested with several governments from September 2008. Since Autumn 2009, a rebate mechanism for developing countries emerged as the preferred option (not described in the paper).

The main challenge addressed is how to provide global rules and policies for international transport while delivering on the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities embodied in the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol. We propose to differentiate obligations and link together adaptation to climate change, emission mitigation, technology transformation, and financing in one single scheme. Differentiated emission charges will apply to reflect the climate change regime in force (currently differentiated by import for Annex I / non-Annex I).
The paper concludes:

  • The deadlock to address emissions from international maritime transport can be resolved through the proposed architecture, balancing the interests of all parties.
  • The proposed can be used to hammer out the maritime deal on the right political level - and in time for the key Copenhagen Climate Change Talks in 2009. Otherwise, the risk of inaction is twofold:
    1. repeat Kyoto’s failure to address international transport emissions, and
    2. fail to provide financing for adaptation to climate change crucially needed for the most vulnerable.

Presented at the online Climate 2008 Conference (Paper 72).

An abstract is provided below. The paper is structured as follows:

  1. The introduction discusses whether the existing policy deadlock presents an opportunity to address climate change in a holistic manner.
  2. Section 2 proposes six architectural principles which will be central to unlock common but differentiated responsibilities for international transport. It also quantifies benefits and costs to participating countries, and discusses equity issues.
  3. Section 3 builds a feasible instrument that could deliver the proposed architecture.
  4. Finally, Section 4 considers how the existing legal laws and precedents can enable early action.

Reconciling Positions - Solution for Annex I Parties


The option to narrow the architecture on the collection side to countries with emission reduction commitments - currently Annex I countries to the UNFCCC - is not fully covered in the paper. It is shortly discussed in section 4.1.5, Improving Differentiation Further.
Limiting the scope to Annex-I countries will reduce the total benefits to 60% from the numbers provided. Ships while transporting goods to Annex I countries will pay the emission charges, and while transporting goods to non-Annex I countries will not. Ships operating on mixed routes will pay 60% of the full fees, on average.

The need to reconsider such a less-efficient option has appeared after the recent first IMO Intersessional Meeting of the Working Group on Greenhouse Gas Emissions from ships in Oslo (IMO GHG WG 1). The session was tough, and the European Federation for Transport and Environment called it disappointing. It was not possible to bridge the principles of the IMO of providing global and uniform rules while delivering on the differentiated principles embodied in the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol. As a result, it was not possible to further develop an economic instrument based either on the submissions for a levy/hybrid scheme or on submissions for an emission trading scheme (ETS).

Abstract

This paper proposes an architecture to address emissions from international maritime transport and potentially from aviation in the post-2012 international climate regime.
Shipping emissions are large – more than double the emissions from aviation. Together they currently constitute about 5-6% of global greenhouse gas emissions from fossil fuels, and are growing fast. These emissions are not covered by the Kyoto Protocol and attempts to define a global policy to address them have so far failed.
Current financial mechanisms for adaptation to climate change aimed at helping the world’s poor deal with the consequences of global warming are inadequate, in both design and scale. The adaptation needs of developing countries are estimated at tens of $billions per annum – the funding gap is currently about 100 times higher than all anticipated contributions.
The main challenges for the architecture are identified. Most importantly: how to provide global uniform rules and policies for international transport while delivering on the differentiated approach embodied in the UNFCCC and the Kyoto Protocol.
To resolve the deadlock the proposed architecture links together adaptation, mitigation, technology and financing in one single scheme. Six architectural principles form the foundation of the scheme and are proposed to ensure equity. The first principle is: Mitigation and adaptation will be treated as equally important, and therefore funds aggregated through an economic instrument will be split between the two. The remaining principles cover mitigation, adaptation, longer-term transformational changes, a long-term emission goal, and a supra-national approach. The impact of the architecture on the developing and developed countries is quantified based on import freight costs. Developed countries will bear most of the costs with little direct benefits. Conversely, developing countries will gain twice of what they put in – a benefit factor of 2. The Least Developed Countries will gain most, in total 15% of monies raised. The resulting distribution of costs is shown to fulfil the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities and respective capabilities.
A new cap-and-charge instrument is introduced to deliver the proposed architecture. It is based on a flat emission charge which is driven by a quantitative emission goal for the entire maritime sector. The International Maritime Emission Reduction Scheme based on the cap-and-charge, simultaneously eliminates the methodological barriers of emission allocations and cap-and-trade, provides incentives to secure global participation, and is easy to implement within existing maritime legal frameworks. It is also flexible enough to differentiate between emission costs for importing subsistence versus merchant goods, bringing equity differentiation at the individual level. The cost impact for different stakeholders is provided with the end user impact estimated at 0.1% on prices of imported goods. The cost of inaction for the developing countries is quantified as $4bn annually of adaptation financing not made available to the most vulnerable countries.
The paper highlights that a precedent for supra-national charges already exists (IOPC Funds) and the existing MARPOL convention can provide a platform for early action. It also suggests ways in which similar approach could be applied to international aviation.
The paper concludes that the deadlock to address emissions from international maritime transport can be unlocked through the proposed architecture, balancing the interests of all parties.

Improving Differentiation Further

Even though the proposed basic architecture provides significant direct benefits and several differentiation mechanisms it may be seen by some as not fully delivering on differentiated responsibilities.
Providing a flexible instrument is deployed, additional differentiation could be added at the collection point. IMERS additional differentiation could be as follows, in a given period of time:

  • Ships transporting goods only to Annex I countries pay 100% of emission charges;
  • Ships transporting goods only to non-Annex I countries pay zero (0);
  • Ships transporting goods to both types of countries pay a variable charge based on relevant mix of transport work (world average just under 60%).
The cost of emissions would most likely be recovered through increased freight prices on imports to Annex I countries only, thereby resolving the differentiation issue at hand.

Global but Differentiated Principle and Policy have been developed accordingly (It's new, and is seen as a breakthrough approach).

A narrower scope could reduce the environmental effectiveness and amount of funding aggregated. This would depend on the stringency of the goal applied. For the goal staying the same, the total benefits would be around 60% of the numbers provided earlier. For instance the amount of adaptation funding would be $2.4bn rather than $4bn annually (a very good result, and much better than the current 0 resulting from the existing deadlock).
A binary differentiation may even be replaced with country-specific obligation factors. These are typically defined in relation to responsibilities and capabilities, but so far have been only proposed to address equity of emission allocations (see for instance: the Greenhouse Development Rights Framework).

Conclusion

In conclusion, the deadlock to address emissions from international maritime transport can be resolved through the proposed architecture, balancing the interests of all parties.
The cap-and-charge instrument has been shown to be flexible, efficient and effective. Importantly, it has already gained support from several states.
The legal precedence for supra-national charges already exists in shipping through the IOPC Funds. The process to implement amendments to existing maritime environmental regimes can be as quick as 16 months.
The proposed architecture can be used to hammer out the maritime deal on the right political level - and in time for the key Copenhagen Climate Change Talks in 2009. Otherwise, the risk of inaction is twofold: repeat Kyoto’s failure to address international transport emissions, and fail to provide financing for adaptation to climate change crucially needed for the most vulnerable.